Persistent unilateral action

Persistent unilateral action (DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/psrm.2024.37) was written by David Foster in 2025. It was published in Political Science Research and Methods (vol. 13, no. 3).

The author explores why some executive orders issued by U.S. presidents have lasting impact on policy, while others are reverted immediately.

The author analyses this problem in terms of policy-seeking groups. If a group has enough political power, they can compel the government to either enact an executive order or pass legislation. The core assumption is that legislation is more lasting, so is preferrable, but also requires greater power.

The hypothesis is that the persistence of executive orders is predicted by how the relevant policy-seeking group's power changed over time. The author is especially interested on formulating a policy feedback effect whereby an executive order empowers the group, or enables the group to empower itself, leading to a situation where the next administration has no effective option to revert.

The author uses a game theory model formulated as:

As for the budget...

The game is then simplified by assumptions:

Altogether, the interesting interaction in this game is the level of expenditures kt,i selected by group i in round t. The executive order route will give a more preferential policy to L, as compared to the legislative route. A powerful L (i.e., high αL relative to αR) will vary between aiming for either of the two, depending on how much feedback that can be extracted from the preferential policy. A weak L (i.e., relatively low αL) can only pursue an executive order.

Varying the exogenous β parameter is critical to the author's area of interest. As expected, the higher this term's value, the more likely an executive order will persist. Also, the higher this term's value, the more likely L will pursue the executive order route.

Reading Notes

First of all, the budget constraint is shoddy. One of these must be true:

  1. groups can have negative budgets
  2. the slope β * dF/dx is shallow enough that Congress could never move xt far enough to bankrupt a group's budget

    • presidents are already constrained by ±d, so Congress is the risky actor here

I don't think (1) makes sense under any interpretation of what the 'budget' actually is. (2) means that the starting point dominates feedback. I think that the author has hand-waved this away by focusing so much (too much?) on the left-leaning group's incentives, and the game is designed that the left-leaning group is always ascendant in round 1.

The whole 'budget' thing is written so vaguely. It could mean campaign contributions, it could mean mobilizing electoral resources, it could mean trading votes in elections. I assume this was done to sidestep criticisms from any singular direction. But the paper would be so much easier to reason about if the author picked one.

The biggest issue is the equivalence between policy, political power, and politicians' utility. If the 'budget' were trading votes, for example, the implication becomes that politicians gain utility from both policy preferences and security in elections. But while feasible, there must be diminishing returns to the 'security in elections' component there.

If the 'budget' were campaign contributions, the equivalence between policy and political power is very questionable. There is considerable informal evidence that (the appearance of) moving policy in one direction mobilizes opponents, whereas the feedback theory relies upon there being a demobilizing effect following such an outcome.


CategoryRicottone CategoryReadingNotes

PersistentUnilateralAction (last edited 2025-08-11 14:33:44 by DominicRicottone)