Is It the Message or the Messenger? Examining Movement in Immigration Beliefs

Is It the Message or the Messenger? Examining Movement in Immigration Beliefs was written by Hassan Afrouzi, Carolina Arteaga, and Emily Weisburst. It was published in the Journal of Political Economy Microeconomics volume 2 (2024).

The authors design an experiment to isolate the effects of political messages and the effects of who gave the political message. Pro- and anti-immigration speeches, as well as non-ideological (turkey pardoning) speeches, are selected from Obama and Trump. The same speeches are reproduced with a voice actor. The non-ideological speeches enable control for effects of political messages. The reproduction enables control for the effects of who gave the political message.

Probability Theory

A sample space Ω represents an individual's opinion about immigration (binary; favorable or unfavorable). Subjective opinions--as in given S sources of political messages and M expected messages from each source--are given in Ω‾ = Ω * M * S.

The unconditional probability of belief ω is given by P(ω) = Σ P(ω,s',m') for all s' ∈ S and m' ∈ M.

For a 'treatment' s' ∈ S and m' ∈ M, the conditional probability of belief ω is given by P(ω|s',m').

It is more realistic to measure relative probabilities of beliefs in an experiment, however. Therefore the treatment belief relative to the unconditional belief is given by:

equation1.svg

Decomposition of Anonymous Message Effects and Source Persuasion Effects

We can measure unconditional beliefs P(ω), beliefs given an anonymous message P(ω|m), and beliefs given a message from a source P(ω|m,s).

Decompose the first equation with Bayes rule and log probabilities into separate anonymous message effects and source persuasion effects:

equation2.svg

Again by Bayes rule, decompose the conditional probabilities:

equation3.svg

...or using an odds ratio (Θ) formulation:

P(ω|m) = P(ω)Θ(m|ω)

This is an immediately useful formulation: the anonymous message effect βm increases with the odds ratio Θ(m|ω) and is zero iff the odds ratio is one.

Similarly now:

equation4.svg

Note furthermore that:

equation5.svg

Lastly, understand that for all s ∈ S there is a complementary ¬s such that:

P(w|m) = P(w,s|m) + P(w,¬s|m) = P(s|m)P(w|s,m) + P(¬s|m)P(w|¬s,m)

This all comes together to calculate the source persuasion effect βms which increases with the odds ratio Θ(s|m,ω) and is zero iff the odds ratio is one. As an intermediary step:

There is a source persuasion effect iff:

Θ(s|m,ω) > 1

...which can be more easily worked with as:

Θ(s|m,ω) - 1 > 0

Substitute the left-hand side's odds ratio Θ(s|m,ω) and combine terms:

equation6.svg

Substitute the numerator's term P(ω|m) with the expanded expression above:

equation7.svg

Factor out the redundant term:

equation8.svg

Decompose with the complementary rule and factor out that term:

equation9.svg

This is interpreted as:

However, it is possible for prior beliefs to be zero. As a result, it's necessary to re-map this to terms of log probabilities plus 1:

equation10.svg

Decomposition of Source Priming Effects

We can additionally measure beliefs given a non-political (turkey pardoning) message m0. If this is truly an independent message, then P(ω|m0,s) = P(ω|s).

Returning to the first equation, decompose into separate source priming effects and identified message effects:

equation11.svg


CategoryRicottone